Saturday 21 April 2012

Proportional Representation: Can an Electoral System Undermine Democracy?


Imane Drissi El-Bouzaidi
November 1, 2011
            In 1990, the French President Francois Mitterrand, announced that French aid would be “less enthusiastic to regimes which behave in an authoritarian fashion and fail to accept the move towards democracy.”[i] Incentives, such as these, often encourage states to democratize, but in many cases the transformation is illusory because electoral systems can be manipulated to serve specific interests. This essay will focus on the List Proportional Representation (List PR) electoral system and how it can be manipulated and used as a tool to undermine democracy. By using the case study of Morocco, it will be argued that List PR can be used to fragment the opposition, thereby providing certain groups with unfair advantage or non-contested dominance, while maintaining the guise of democracy. The case study will focus solely on the post-2002 electoral system in Morocco, when List PR was adopted. Firstly, the dynamics of the electoral system will be explained, and then secondly how List PR affects the political system by causing fragmentation, weakening political parties, and dividing the opposition.
 Dynamics of a PR System:
            The Moroccan case study has a bicameral parliament, with the Assembly of Councillors and the Assembly of Representatives.[ii] The Assembly of Councillors is indirectly elected by local councils, professional chambers, and wage-earners; whereas, the Assembly of Representatives consists of 325 members, directly elected by Moroccan citizens. Both chambers are important because they each need to approve legislation in order for it to be passed but this paper will focus solely on the Assembly of Representatives because the members are directly elected using List PR.[iii]
            The Largest Remainder method with a Hare-Clark quota is also used for allocating votes into seats. The percentage of votes that each party receives is proportional to the percentage of seats that they obtain, yet a party is required to obtain more votes than the electoral average (the Hare-Clark quota) in order to obtain a seat.[iv] Once a party reaches the electoral average and receives a seat, it can receive a second seat only if its remaining votes are higher than the original votes of the other parties in the district. If no party reaches the electoral average, then the seats are determined by which party receives the highest number of votes. Parties must also pass a threshold, which was raised from three percent in 2002 to six percent in 2007, in order to obtain a seat. 
            Morocco’s electoral system has two tiers: a local list and a national list. Out of 325 seats, 295 are elected by local lists through multi-member districts; whereas, 30 seats are reserved solely for women and are elected from a national list.[v] In 2007, a maximum magnitude of five seats in each district was established and the number of districts was increased to 95.[vi] The ballot is structured as a single-ballot, closed, party-list; therefore, voters can only choose their preferred party as opposed to a specific candidate and only the parties have control over the order of the candidates in their list.[vii]

Effect of a PR system on Politics:
            The ballot structure, formula, and magnitude of a PR electoral system have major impacts on a state’s political system. These impacts can be both positive and negative. Some advantages of a PR system are that it encourages the inclusion of smaller parties and produces a more representative legislature.[viii] This is evident in Morocco because there are many small parties who were able to obtain a seat. In the 2007 elections, 17 parties received less than 10 seats (3% of the vote) and in total 33 different parties received seats. In addition, the quota for women led to a significant increase in representation from two women to thirty-five in 2002.[ix] List PR also decreases the wasted vote because strategic voting is not as essential. As a result, this electoral system should lead to greater voter turnout because all votes go directly to the party of choice. However, the fact that in 2007, voter participation in Morocco was at 37% with a high percentage of spoiled/protest ballots makes this point important to analyze.[x]
            Voter apathy was not attributed to unfair elections because international observers were present and they declared that the elections were “open and competitive.”[xi] The reason for the low turnout is instead a response to the PR electoral system and how “it is engineered to prevent any single party from emerging with a majority.”[xii] The general trend of List PR is to generate a multi-party system with weaker parties as opposed to the plurality system. This is problematic in Morocco because the king holds major power in the political system; therefore, weak parties are more easily controlled by the king and are unable to provide adequate checks and balances. The king uses the PR system as a tool to maintain power by dividing, creating, and co-opting parties. This prevents them from unifying successfully and presenting a strong opposition against the king. List PR also helps the king escape blame for bad policymaking because in a system with many parties there are many actors, which leads to less clarity of responsibility.[xiii] Ultimately “the elected chamber of parliament has limited ability to effect change” and this will persist unless stronger parties or coalitions begin forming to oppose the king.[xiv]
            The fragmentation of the political system due to List PR is evident in Morocco because between 1963 and 1997 it was using a First-Past-the-Post system. Although the political system was still somewhat fragmented with the plurality system, this was attributed to vote rigging by the king. However, with the change to List PR, there was a major increase in the number of parties 14 to 26 parties, and the fact that the elections were declared to be fair, means that the outcome was a result of the electoral system or voting preferences as opposed to electoral fraud.
            There are many ways in which the monarch uses List PR as a tool to fragment the opposition. Firstly, the Largest Remainder method and the Hare quota are used because they are more advantageous for smaller parties than the Alternative method.[xv] This formula makes it extremely difficult for a party to receive more than one seat in a district because there are a large number of parties that compete in the elections and the electoral average is high.[xvi] Evidence of this is during the 2007 elections because in 87 out of the 95 multi-member districts, no party was able to win a second seat.[xvii] The legislature becomes fragmented with many parties holding a small number of seats.
            The delimitation of a district is another aspect of the electoral system that is manipulated to cause fragmentation. In Morocco, districts are unequal in the number of votes needed to receive to obtain a seat, varying from as few as 4000 votes to as many as 80,000 per seat (NDI 19). The changes in the delimitation of districts were also used strategically against an opposition party to “reduce the possible triumph of the [Parti de la Justice et du Développement], since it affected the constituencies where this party had had two seats.”[xviii] Therefore, reshaping constituencies can be a strategic tool to fragment an opposition party.
            Morocco is not a unique case in its use of List PR as a tool to fragment the opposition, but rather Cameroon is another example among others. Since 1990, Cameroon uses List PR to fragment the opposition in order to maintain uncontested dominance for a single party, the Cameroon People’s Democratic Movement (CPDM). The electoral system differs though in that it is parallel with single-list districts elected by plurality Party Block Vote (PBV) and multi-member districts elected by a List PR system. The plurality tier is used to allow the CPDM to consolidate power because it is strategically used in districts that favour the party so the party that wins a majority obtains all the seats in the district.[xix] The PR tier is used is in districts popular to opposition parties so that the votes are split between different parties, which fragments the opposition and allows the CPDM to maintain dominance. Therefore, PR is again used as a tool to weaken opposition parties and ensure that they have no significant chance of gaining power.
            In conclusion, this essay has argued that the List PR electoral system can be used as a tool to fragment the opposition in order to allow leaders or groups to maintain dominance over the political system. This has been evident in Morocco with the domination of the monarch over policy making and Cameroon with the domination of the CPDM. Although multipartyism has many advantages, it can also undermine democracy because an effective system has an opposition that can “challenge the ruling parties on all issues of governance and provide alternatives to existing policies.”[xx] In order to recognize that democratic systems can be illusory, it is important to understand that actors use electoral systems to advantage themselves and this has certainly been the case in certain PR systems and must be addressed for a fair and democratic system to prevail.


[i]  John Mukum Mbaku and Joseph Takougang, eds., The Leadership Challenge in Africa: Cameroon under Paul Biya (Trenton, N.J.: Africa World Pr, 2004), 464.
[ii]  “Final Report On the Moroccan Legislative Elections,” National Democratic Institute(September 7 2007), http://www.ndi.org/files/2316_ma_report_electionsfinal_en_051508_1.pdf (accessed November 1, 2011) 9.
[iii] Ibid
[iv] Ibid, 40
[v] Said Kirhlani, “Electoral Report: Morocco Parliamentary Elections,” TEIM Election Watch Analysis (February 11, 2009): 4.
[vi] NDI, 8
[vii] NDI, 40
[viii] Andrew Reynolds, Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis, Electoral System Design: The New International IDEA Handbook (Stockholm, Sweden: International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance 2005, 2008), 59.
[ix] NDI, 17
[x] NDI, 18
[xi] Michael Meyer-Resende, “Is the Moroccan Electoral System Unfair?” Carnegie Endowment for International Peace (April 12, 2008) http://carnegieendowment.org/2008/08/12/is-moroccan-electoral-system-unfair/6d9d(accessed November 1, 2011).
[xii] Ibid
[xiii] IDEA, 59.
[xiv] NDI, 13
[xv] IDEA, 178.
[xvi] Kirhlani, 4.
[xvii] NDI, 10
[xviii] Kirhlani, 7.
[xix] Mbaku, 461
[xx] Mbaku, 472








No comments:

Post a Comment